Weaponizing Trade: Trump’s Tariff Tantrum and the Collapse of International Economic Order

By Professor Habib Al-Badawi, Mohamed Hani, Ouahiba Louahab

As we enter the mid-2020s, the global economic landscape bears little resemblance to the optimistic visions of liberal internationalism that dominated the immediate post-Cold War era. The promise of an integrated global economy—characterized by falling barriers to trade, harmonized regulatory frameworks, and mutual prosperity through comparative advantage—has given way to a fractured system marked by strategic competition, economic nationalism, and the deliberate weaponization of economic interdependence. This transformation reflects not merely a temporary deviation from established norms but a fundamental restructuring of the relationship between economic power and geopolitical ambition in the twenty-first century.

The ascendance of Donald Trump to the presidency in 2025 has accelerated these tectonic shifts, with his administration’s sweeping tariff regime representing perhaps the most consequential assault on the liberal trading order since its inception following World War II. By imposing punitive tariffs across the global economy—ranging from 10% on all imports to targeted rates exceeding 50% for strategic competitors—Trump has transformed trade policy from a framework for mutual benefit into an instrument of unilateral power projection. This radical departure from post-war economic orthodoxy signals not only a shift in American policy preferences but a profound reconfiguration of global economic governance itself.

The scale and scope of this transformation cannot be overstated. For seven decades, the liberal economic order underpinned by American leadership provided a relatively stable framework within which nations could pursue development, integration, and prosperity through trade and investment. While imperfect and often reflecting power asymmetries, this system nonetheless operated according to predictable rules, multilateral institutions, and normative constraints on economic coercion. Today, this architecture stands imperiled not primarily by external challengers but by its principal architect—an America increasingly skeptical of the very international institutions and economic principles it once championed.

The consequences reverberate across multiple domains. Financial markets have recorded their steepest declines since 2022, reflecting profound uncertainty regarding future trade relations and supply chain stability. Strategic industries from semiconductors to renewable energy confront disrupted value chains and investment uncertainty. Developing economies navigating already challenging global headwinds now face prohibitive tariffs that threaten export-oriented industrialization pathways. Meanwhile, American consumers—particularly working-class households already struggling with economic insecurity—bear the brunt of what effectively constitutes a massive regressive consumption tax.

Beyond these immediate impacts lies a more fundamental transformation in how economic power functions within international relations. Trade measures historically designed to address specific market distortions or unfair practices have been reconceptualized as instruments of political leverage—creating artificial economic pain that can be selectively alleviated in exchange for concessions across multiple domains. This weaponization strategy subordinates economic logic to political calculus, creating unprecedented concentrations of discretionary power and undermining the predictability essential for efficient market functioning.

As the liberal economic order fragments under sustained assault from its once-steadfast champion, critical questions emerge regarding the future trajectory of global economic governance. Can a system predicated on rules-based cooperation survive the withdrawal of its principal guarantor? How will rising powers—particularly China—respond to American economic coercion? What recourse remains for middle powers and developing economies caught between competing great power economic blocs? And perhaps most fundamentally, can economic interdependence still serve as a foundation for peace and prosperity in an era of intensifying geopolitical competition?

This analysis endeavors to address these questions through a comprehensive examination of Trump’s tariff regime—its structure, its impacts, and its implications for the future of international economic relations. Far from a temporary aberration or negotiating tactic, these policies represent a fundamental reconfiguration of how economic power is conceived, deployed, and contested in twenty-first century international relations. Understanding this transformation requires moving beyond conventional economic analysis to examine the intersection of trade policy, political strategy, and geopolitical competition that increasingly defines our fractured global economy.

Theoretical Framework:

 Geo-Economic Statecraft and Trade Weaponization

The theoretical foundation of this analysis operates at the intersection of geo-economics, international political economy, and strategic trade theory. This framework conceptualizes Trump’s tariff policies not merely as economic measures but as sophisticated instruments of statecraft within an evolving landscape of global power competition.

Geo-Economics as an Analytical Foundation

The analysis builds upon Blackwill and Harris’s (2016) conceptualization of “geo-economics” as the deliberate use of economic instruments to promote national interests and generate beneficial geopolitical outcomes. This perspective recognizes that in the post-Cold War era, states increasingly deploy economic mechanisms—trade policy, investment restrictions, sanctions, and monetary policy—to pursue strategic objectives traditionally sought through military means.

As Luttwak (1990) articulated in his foundational work, geo-economics represents “the logic of conflict with the grammar of commerce.” This framework illuminates how Trump’s tariffs function beyond nominal economic objectives as mechanisms of power projection and coercive leverage within international relations. The tariff regime exemplifies what Farrell and Newman (2019) term “weaponized interdependence”—the strategic exploitation of asymmetric network positions to extract concessions and reshape power dynamics in the international system.

Strategic Trade Theory and Political Leverage

Building upon Krugman’s (1986) work on strategic trade policy and Baldwin’s (1985) economic statecraft framework, this analysis examines how tariffs operate as sophisticated tools for extracting concessions and restructuring bilateral relationships. Unlike classical free trade theory, which emphasizes mutual gains through comparative advantage, strategic trade theory recognizes that governments may intervene in specific markets to shift economic rents and secure national advantage.

Trump’s approach, however, represents a radical extension of strategic trade thinking—deploying tariffs not as targeted interventions in specific sectors but as broad instruments of political leverage. Drawing on Hirschman’s (1945) classic analysis of asymmetric interdependence, we can discern how the administration leverages America’s market power to create “artificial economic pain” that can be selectively alleviated through exemptions and bilateral negotiations.

Institutional Power and Regime Transformation

The framework incorporates Ikenberry’s (2011) analysis of liberal international orders to examine how Trump’s policies challenge institutional arrangements that have governed trade relations since World War II. By undermining the World Trade Organization, withdrawing from multilateral agreements, and imposing unilateral tariffs, Trump has accelerated the exploitation of asymmetric network positions to gain strategic advantage.

This approach employs Drezner’s (2021) concept of “the power of economic statecraft” to analyze how these policies reflect a fundamental reconfiguration of America’s relationship with the liberal trade order it helped establish. As Drezner argues, economic coercion works through both material impacts and signaling effects—creating uncertainty that alters risk calculations across global markets.

Distributional Politics and Domestic Consequences

The framework also incorporates insights from Ruggie’s (1982) “embedded liberalism” compromise and Rodrik’s (2011) “globalization paradox” to examine the domestic distributional consequences of trade weaponization. These perspectives help explain how tariff policies that ostensibly aim to protect domestic industries often impose regressive burdens on working-class constituencies through increased consumer prices and disrupted supply chains.

Drawing on Autor, Dorn, and Hanson’s (2013) influential work on the “China shock,” this framework illuminates the complex interplay between legitimate concerns about trade-induced dislocation and politically motivated economic nationalism that sacrifices systemic stability for short-term political advantage.

The deployment of tariffs as instruments of economic statecraft represents a critical inflection point in the evolution of great power competition in the twenty-first century. Through this critical lens, we interrogate the motives, mechanisms, and outcomes of Trump’s tariff strategy, evaluating its profound implications not only for immediate commercial relations but also for global economic governance, institutional stability, and the future trajectory of international relations.

The administration’s use of tariffs as blunt-force tools of foreign policy has strained diplomatic relationships, fractured traditional alliances, and fundamentally challenged the architectural underpinnings of economic globalization. By strategically weaponizing trade policy, Trump has signaled an unprecedented willingness to sacrifice the stability of the international economic system in pursuit of narrowly defined national interests and short-term political calculations. This approach marks a stark deviation from decades of American leadership in promoting open markets and rules-based trade.

The geo-economic framework reveals how Trump’s tariff policies function as mechanisms of power projection and strategic leverage beyond their nominal economic objectives. By creating artificial economic pain that can be selectively alleviated through exemptions and bilateral negotiations, these measures establish a coercive dynamic that subordinates commercial logic to political calculus. This weaponization strategy transforms trade policy from a collaborative framework for mutual benefit into a unilateral instrument for extracting concessions, disciplining allies, and projecting dominance in international relations.

Moreover, Trump’s approach represents a fundamental reconfiguration of America’s relationship with the liberal international order it helped establish—one predicated on the belief that economic interdependence through trade liberalization would foster prosperity, peace, and stability between nations. The administration’s systematic dismantling of this architecture through withdrawal from multilateral agreements, attacks on the World Trade Organization, and imposition of unilateral tariffs signals a dramatic reordering of American priorities and a willingness to embrace economic nationalism even at the cost of systemic instability.

Trump’s Tariff Regime: Structure and Scope

The scale and scope of Trump’s latest tariff regime represent an extraordinary departure from conventional trade policy norms. The administration’s announcement of a comprehensive 10% global tariff on imports, supplemented by significantly higher “reciprocal” tariffs targeting dozens of countries, has sent shockwaves through global markets and diplomatic corridors alike. This unprecedented move effectively transforms trade policy from a scalpel—precisely targeted to address specific market distortions or unfair practices—into a sledgehammer indiscriminately striking at the foundations of the global trading system.

The cumulative impact on individual trading partners is severe and wide-ranging. China—long positioned as America’s primary economic rival—faces a particularly punishing 54% tariff rate, incorporating both the 20% duties imposed earlier and an additional 34% tax calculated under Trump’s novel “tit-for-tat” formula. The European Union, despite its status as a longstanding American ally and security partner, confronts a substantial 20% rate. Vietnam, which has emerged as an alternative manufacturing hub as companies seek to diversify supply chains away from China, now grapples with a prohibitive 46% tariff burden.

White House documents reveal similarly severe tariff rates imposed across a diverse array of U.S. trading partners: Japan at 24%, South Korea at 25%, India at 26%, Cambodia at 49%, and Taiwan at 32%. This sweeping application of punitive duties reflects not a calibrated response to specific trade grievances but rather a comprehensive repudiation of the principles of trade liberalization that have governed international commerce for generations. The indiscriminate nature of these tariffs—affecting allies and strategic competitors alike—suggests objectives extending far beyond conventional trade policy considerations.

Particularly striking is the administration’s methodological approach to calculating these “reciprocal” tariffs. The Trump team’s formula—dividing America’s trade deficit with each country by their exports to the United States to derive a purported measure of unfair trade practices—has no foundation in economic theory or empirical evidence. This arbitrary methodology allows the administration to present punitive tariffs as justifiable responses to unfair trade practices when they represent capricious impositions disconnected from any coherent economic reasoning or legitimate strategic trade objectives.

This approach reflects a fundamental misunderstanding—or deliberate misrepresentation—of how trade deficits function within the global economy. Bilateral trade balances are not inherently indicative of unfair practices but rather reflect complex patterns of production, consumption, investment, and currency valuations across interconnected economies. By reducing this multidimensional reality to a simplistic calculation that purportedly justifies punitive tariffs, the administration has effectively abandoned evidence-based policymaking in favor of a narrative that portrays the United States as a victim of predatory trade practices requiring forceful unilateral redress.

Market Reactions and Economic Impacts

The market response to Trump’s tariff announcements has been swift and severe, underscoring the profound destabilizing potential of these policies. Financial markets, which function as forward-looking indicators of economic expectations, have rendered an unambiguous verdict on the administration’s approach—one that signals deep concern regarding the trajectory of global trade relations and supply chain stability.

In Europe, the regional STOXX 600 index temporarily plummeted by approximately 2.7%, while continental European markets suffered even deeper losses, with France’s CAC 40 and Germany’s DAX recording precipitous drops of 3.3% and 3.1%, respectively. These market contractions reflect not merely short-term volatility but profound uncertainty regarding future trade relations with the United States—uncertainty that complicates investment decisions, supply chain planning, and economic forecasting across the European continent.

American markets demonstrated similarly pronounced vulnerability, with broad market indices falling 4%—their worst performance since September 2022. The decline was notably comprehensive across market sectors, with declining stocks on the New York Stock Exchange outpacing advancing securities by a ratio of 6 to 1. This widespread market contraction indicates that investors have priced in significant economic disruption because of escalating trade hostilities, reflecting a fundamental loss of confidence in the stability of global commercial relationships.

However, stock market performance provides an incomplete and potentially misleading indicator of economic impact. More concerning is the disproportionate impact on ordinary American households, who will inevitably bear the brunt of these policies as import taxes are passed through supply chains to manifest as higher prices for everyday consumer goods.

This regressive effect is particularly troubling given the administration’s rhetorical commitment to working-class economic interests. By imposing what effectively constitutes a massive consumption tax on imported goods—products that compose a larger share of expenditure for lower-income households—these tariffs create a distributional impact that disproportionately precisely burdens those Americans the administration claims to champion.

Beyond immediate market reactions and consumer impacts, the tariffs threaten to disrupt complex global supply chains that have evolved over decades of increasing economic integration. Modern manufacturing processes frequently involve components crossing multiple borders before final assembly, with production stages distributed across countries to maximize efficiency and minimize costs. By abruptly imposing substantial tariffs across this intricate network, the administration has introduced profound uncertainty that compromises investment planning, disrupts established business relationships, and ultimately threatens both productivity and employment across interconnected global industries.

The False Premise of Tariff Reciprocity

Central to understanding the intellectual incoherence of Trump’s tariff policy is examining the administration’s dubious justification for these measures. The claim of tariff “reciprocity” reflects not an evidence-based approach to addressing legitimate trade imbalances but rather a fundamental misapplication of economic concepts and methodological sleight of hand designed to present arbitrary impositions as principled responses to unfair treatment.

Trade deficits reflect complex macroeconomic factors, including relative savings rates, investment patterns, currency valuations, and comparative advantages—not necessarily unfair trade practices or barriers. To derive tariff rates from deficit calculations represents a categorically flawed approach that economists across the ideological spectrum have unanimously rejected.

This assessment captures not merely a technical error but a profound intellectual dishonesty at the heart of the administration’s trade policy—one that subordinates economic reasoning to political calculation and narrative construction. The administration’s inconsistent benchmarks and timelines for tariffs further reveal that these measures function not as calibrated tools of industrial policy, but as political instruments deployed tactically to project strength, extract concessions, and generate leverage, regardless of their economic rationality or long-term consequences for American prosperity.

Legitimate tariff policies might focus on specific sectors where unfair practices occur, incorporate clear objectives and metrics for success, establish pathways for resolution, and exist within broader strategies for enhancing competitiveness and supporting affected workers. Trump’s approach demonstrates none of these characteristics, instead wielding tariffs as punitive instruments disconnected from coherent economic strategy.

This distinction between strategic tariffs and weaponized trade policy is crucial for understanding the administration’s approach. While tariffs can serve as legitimate tools for addressing specific market distortions or supporting strategic industries, their effectiveness depends on careful calibration, clear objectives, and integration within comprehensive policy frameworks. Trump’s “reciprocal” tariffs meet none of these criteria, functioning instead as arbitrary impositions justified through methodological contortions and misleading rhetoric about trade fairness.

Distributional Consequences and Fiscal Impact

Perhaps most concerning is the regressive distributional impact of Trump’s tariff regime. Far from advancing the economic interests of working-class Americans as claimed, these tariffs effectively constitute a massive, highly regressive tax increase that disproportionately burdens low- and middle-income households. The fiscal implications of this approach are staggering, potentially reaching a trillion dollars annually, equivalent to approximately $7,000 per household.

This extraordinary fiscal burden will primarily affect middle- and low-income households while easing the relative burden on the wealthy, who spend proportionally less of their income on imported goods. This regressive incidence reflects a fundamental economic reality: lower-income households typically devote a larger proportion of their income to consumption rather than savings, and within their consumption patterns, imported goods comprise a substantial share. From clothing and household appliances to food and medicine, everyday necessities frequently incorporate imported components or materials that would be directly affected by tariff increases.

This regressive distributional impact reveals a fundamental contradiction in the administration’s economic approach. While professing concern for American workers and manufacturing communities, the policies enacted systematically transfer wealth from ordinary consumers to protected industries and their shareholders—a transfer that disproportionately benefits those at the upper end of the income and wealth distribution.

This represents not merely an economic miscalculation but a profound betrayal of the working-class constituencies whose economic anxieties helped propel Trump to power. Moreover, the scale of this effective tax increase stands in stark contrast to the administration’s rhetoric regarding tax relief and economic stimulus. The trillion-dollar annual burden these tariffs potentially impose dwarfs the tax reductions implemented earlier in Trump’s tenure, effectively negating their stimulative impact while introducing significant distortions into consumption patterns and investment decisions.

Beyond their immediate distributional impact, these tariffs threaten to trigger inflationary pressures that would further erode real wages and purchasing power for American workers. As import prices rise in response to tariff increases, these costs inevitably propagate through supply chains, ultimately manifesting as higher consumer prices across a wide range of goods. This inflationary effect compounds the regressive nature of the tariff burden, further constraining household budgets already stretched thin by rising costs for housing, healthcare, education, and other essentials.

Global Repercussions: 

Allies, Adversaries, and the Global South

The international ramifications of Trump’s tariff tantrum extend far beyond immediate market reactions and consumer impacts, fundamentally destabilizing global economic relationships and institutional arrangements. While much analysis has focused on impacts within advanced economies, particularly the United States and European Union, the consequences for vulnerable economies in the Global South merit equally thoughtful consideration.

This assessment highlights the often-overlooked asymmetric impact of trade hostilities on developing economies—nations with limited capacity to absorb economic shocks, diversify export markets, or leverage countervailing power against U.S. pressure. For countries like Cambodia, facing a punitive 49% tariff rate, or Vietnam at 46%, such measures threaten to devastate export-oriented industries that serve as crucial pathways for economic development and poverty reduction. Unlike advanced economies with diversified markets and robust social safety nets, these nations possess limited buffers against the economic dislocation that punitive tariffs may trigger—potentially reverse decades of development progress and exacerbating global inequality.

Even among traditional allies and strategic partners, Trump’s approach has provoked profound concern and reevaluation of relationships with the United States. The United Kingdom’s experience provides a particularly illuminating case study in the diplomatic futility of attempting to appease the administration’s transactional approach to international relations. Despite extensive diplomatic overtures and the promise of a privileged bilateral trade relationship following Brexit, the UK has not received any special treatment, revealing the fundamental instability of an international economic order increasingly dominated by unilateral action rather than predictable rules and reciprocal commitments.

Even more concerning is the administration’s apparent indifference to the destabilizing effects of these policies on traditional alliances and partnerships. By imposing substantial tariffs on the European Union (20%), Japan (24%), South Korea (25%), and other longstanding security partners, Trump has effectively subordinated strategic alliance considerations to narrow commercial interests and domestic political calculations. This approach not only undermines diplomatic capital painstakingly accumulated over decades but also creates openings for strategic competitors—particularly China—to position themselves as more reliable economic partners and champions of multilateral cooperation.

The irony of this situation is profound: while ostensibly designed to counter Chinese economic influence and address unfair trade practices, Trump’s tariff tantrum may ultimately strengthen China’s position by accelerating the fragmentation of the Western-led economic order and undermining confidence in American leadership. As the United States retreats from its historical role as guarantor of open markets and multilateral rules, China has strategically positioned itself as a defender of globalization and predictable trade relationships—a dramatic reversal of traditional roles that reflects the geopolitical consequences of America’s economic nationalism.

Tariffs as Political Leverage: The Weaponization Strategy

U.S. Senator Chris Murphy offers perhaps the most penetrating insight into the true strategic logic underpinning Trump’s tariff regime, observing that these measures are conceived not primarily as instruments of industrial policy but as mechanisms for accumulating and exercising political power. This assessment reveals how tariffs function within Trump’s political economy not as tools for addressing specific market failures or unfair practices, but as mechanisms for creating artificial economic pain that can then be selectively alleviated in exchange for political compliance or economic concessions.

This strategy transforms tariffs from economic policy instruments into tools of political coercion and patronage—a fundamental corruption of governance that subordinates sound economic management to political manipulation. By creating a system where economic relief depends on presidential favor rather than objective criteria or established rules, this approach concentrates unprecedented discretionary power in the executive branch and creates perverse incentives for rent-seeking behavior among affected industries. Companies and sectors facing punitive tariffs are effectively compelled to lobby for exemptions through political channels rather than compete based on economic merits—a dynamic that invites corruption, distorts market signals, and undermines the rule of law in economic governance.

Furthermore, this weaponization strategy fundamentally transforms the relationship between government and the private sector. Rather than providing stable, predictable rules within which businesses can operate efficiently, the administration creates deliberate uncertainty that can only be resolved through direct appeal to political authorities. This approach elevates personal relationships and political connections over market principles, effectively reintroducing elements of mercantilism into modern economic governance. The result is a system where economic outcomes increasingly reflect political calculations rather than market efficiencies—a development that threatens not only economic performance but also democratic accountability and institutional integrity.

The international dimensions of this weaponization strategy are equally concerning. By creating economic pain that can be selectively alleviated through bilateral negotiations, the administration effectively forces trading partners to engage on terms dictated by Washington rather than within multilateral frameworks governed by agreed rules. This approach privileges raw power over legal principles, bilateral deals over multilateral cooperation, and presidential discretion over institutional constraints. The result is a fundamental destabilization of the international economic order—transforming it from a rules-based system providing predictability and fairness into a power-based arrangement where outcomes reflect relative leverage rather than mutual interest or shared principles.

Climate and Energy Implications: 

Fossil Fuel Politics and Renewable Transition

Trump’s tariff regime carries significant implications for global climate objectives and energy transition pathways. This assessment highlights a crucial dimension of the administration’s trade approach—its alignment with fossil fuel interests and hostility toward renewable energy development. While the global energy transition continues to accelerate, driven by technological innovation, cost reductions, and climate imperatives, Trump’s policies effectively handicap American participation in this transformation while imposing additional costs on consumers seeking cleaner energy alternatives. From solar panels and wind turbines to electric vehicles and energy storage systems, many critical components of the clean energy economy incorporate global supply chains that would be directly disrupted by punitive tariffs.

This explicit linkage between trade policy and fossil fuel interests reveals how tariff measures serve not only immediate economic and political objectives but also advance a broader ideological agenda skeptical of climate action and hostile to renewable energy transition. By disrupting global supply chains for renewable energy components and technologies while simultaneously promoting fossil fuel exports, Trump’s policies effectively weaponize trade to impede global decarbonization efforts—a strategy with profound implications for climate mitigation and the future trajectory of global energy systems.

The contradiction between the administration’s professed concern for energy affordability and its policies that effectively increase energy costs reveals a fundamental incoherence in its approach. Tariffs on solar panels, wind turbines, and other renewable energy technologies directly increase their cost to American consumers and businesses while undermining the competitiveness of these increasingly crucial industries. Meanwhile, the promotion of fossil fuel exports, particularly liquefied natural gas, may benefit certain domestic producers but ultimately increases domestic energy prices by linking them more closely to higher international markets—a dynamic that disproportionately impacts lower-income households with the least capacity to absorb increased energy costs.

This approach not only imposes immediate economic costs but also threatens America’s long-term competitiveness in the emerging clean energy economy. As other major economies—particularly China and the European Union—invest aggressively in renewable energy technologies and supportive industrial policies, Trump’s fossil fuel-centric approach risks positioning the United States as a laggard in the industries likely to dominate future global markets. This strategic miscalculation threatens not only climate progress but also American economic competitiveness, job creation, and technological leadership in sectors of growing importance to the global economy.

Systemic Consequences: 

The Fracturing of the Liberal Economic Order

Perhaps most profound are the long-term systemic consequences of Trump’s trade weaponization for the liberal economic order that has underpinned global prosperity for generations. The postwar economic system—characterized by progressively lower trade barriers, predictable rules-based governance, and the primacy of economic over political considerations in commercial relations—faces unprecedented challenges to its foundational assumptions and institutional infrastructure.

This deliberate undermining of the international economic architecture constructed and maintained under decades of American leadership represents a geostrategic inflection point of historic significance. Since 1945, the United States has positioned itself as the principal architect and guarantor of a rules-based economic order predicated on open markets, multilateral institutions, and legal predictability. This system—while imperfect and often reflecting American interests—nonetheless provided a framework within which other nations could pursue development and prosperity through trade and investment, confident that economic relationships would be governed by established rules rather than raw power disparities.

By attacking the World Trade Organization, withdrawing from multilateral agreements, imposing unilateral tariffs, and generally treating international economic institutions with contempt, the Trump administration has accelerated the fragmentation of the global economic system into competing regional blocs and bilateral arrangements. This development paradoxically diminishes rather than enhances America’s ability to shape global economic rules and norms, as other powers—particularly China—move to fill the vacuum created by American retrenchment. From the Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership in Asia to China’s Belt and Road Initiative spanning Eurasia and Africa, alternative institutional arrangements are emerging that exclude American participation and influence, potentially leaving the United States isolated from crucial centers of future economic growth and innovation.

The consequences of this fracturing extend beyond economics into the realm of geopolitical competition and strategic stability. The postwar economic order was never merely an arrangement for managing trade and investment—it represented a grand strategic vision linking economic integration to peace, stability, and American leadership. By embedding former adversaries within a common economic framework and creating shared interests across national boundaries, this system helped prevent the reemergence of great power conflicts and buttressed American hegemony through positive-sum economic arrangements rather than costly military dominance alone.

As this architecture erodes under sustained assault from its principal architect, the risk of renewed great power competition across multiple domains—economic, technological, diplomatic, and potentially military—increases substantially. Economic fragmentation facilitates strategic decoupling, reduces interdependence that historically constrained conflict, and creates conditions where zero-sum thinking predominates over cooperative problem-solving. This dynamic threatens not only economic prosperity but also international stability and security arrangements that have preserved peace among major powers for over seven decades.

Beyond the Tariff Tantrum: 

Recalibrating Global Economic Governance

The geo-economic framework through which we have examined Trump’s tariff policies reveals much more than a momentary deviation from trade orthodoxy—it exposes a fundamental transformation in how economic power is conceived, deployed, and contested in twenty-first-century international relations. As the weaponization of trade accelerates the fragmentation of the post-Cold War economic order, we find ourselves at a critical inflection point that demands both scholarly reckoning and policy innovation.

The evidence assembled throughout this analysis points to a troubling paradox: policies ostensibly designed to strengthen American economic sovereignty have instead accelerated systemic instability that may ultimately diminish America’s capacity to shape global rules and norms. As Blackwill and Harris (2016) might observe, the instrumental use of economic levers without a coherent strategic vision transforms powerful tools into self-defeating weapons. Trump’s tariff regime represents not merely a negotiating tactic but a comprehensive repudiation of the institutional architecture that has magnified American influence for generations.

What emerges from our geo-economic analysis is a vision of international commerce increasingly characterized by what Farrell and Newman (2019) term “weaponized interdependence,” where asymmetric network positions are exploited for coercive advantage rather than mutual prosperity. The transformation of tariffs from instruments of industrial policy into tools of political leverage signals a broader shift from rules-based economic governance toward power-based arrangements that privilege unilateral action over multilateral cooperation.

This transition carries profound implications across multiple domains. Domestically, the regressive distributional impacts of these tariffs contradict their populist justifications, imposing disproportionate burdens on the working-class constituencies they purportedly champion. Internationally, they accelerate strategic decoupling, regional bloc formation, and competing technological spheres that threaten both economic efficiency and geopolitical stability. For the Global South, caught between competing great power economic interests, these developments constrain development pathways and exacerbate vulnerability to external shocks.

Looking forward, the restoration of economic multilateralism will require more than simply reversing Trump’s tariffs or returning to pre-2016 arrangements. As Rodrik’s (2011) globalization paradox suggests, the legitimate concerns about trade dislocation that provided fertile ground for economic nationalism cannot be dismissed through appeals to aggregate welfare gains. Rather, a sustainable international economic architecture must balance openness with policy space, interdependence with resilience, and efficiency with equity.

The challenge before policymakers and scholars alike is to envision economic governance mechanisms that harness the productive potential of global integration while providing democratic legitimacy and distributional fairness. This will require reimagining international economic institutions to better accommodate diverse development models, legitimate security concerns, and the complex intersections between trade, technology, and national security that define contemporary geo-economic competition.

Great Power Competition and Market Structure

The geo-economic reconfiguration triggered by Trump’s tariff regime can be further illuminated through several critical theoretical perspectives that address the intersection of power politics, market structures, and international order. These frameworks provide essential context for understanding the deeper structural forces at work beyond immediate trade disputes.

Allison’s (2017) “Thucydides Trap” thesis offers a compelling lens through which to view current U.S.-China trade tensions. According to Allison, throughout history, when a rising power threatens to displace an established hegemon, the result is often violent conflict. However, in the contemporary context, this competition increasingly manifests through economic rather than military confrontation. Trump’s punitive tariff regime targeting China (54%) represents not merely a trade policy but a strategic response to perceived hegemonic challenges—an attempt to contain China’s economic ascendance through weaponized interdependence. This perspective suggests that tariff policies, rather than isolated economic measures, function as components of a broader structural competition that Allison warns holds significant historical precedent for escalation and conflict.

Complementing this analysis, Mearsheimer’s (2001) offensive realism provides critical insights into why great powers like the United States might abandon institutional commitments in favor of unilateral economic statecraft. Mearsheimer argues that in an anarchic international system, great powers rationally seek regional hegemony and prevent the rise of peer competitors. Trump’s systematic dismantling of multilateral trade architecture can thus be interpreted not as irrational economic nationalism but as a rational attempt to maximize relative power advantages in a system where institutional constraints increasingly limit American freedom of action. This framework helps explain why the administration has prioritized bilateral negotiations (where American market power provides asymmetric advantage) over multilateral forums where institutional rules constrain unilateral action.

While Allison and Mearsheimer provide structural explanations for great power economic competition, Rodrik’s (2017) “Straight Talk on Trade” offers crucial insights into the domestic political dimensions of trade weaponization. Rodrik argues that hyper-globalization has created a fundamental tension between democratic governance, national sovereignty, and economic integration—what he terms the “political trilemma” of the world economy. Trump’s tariff policies represent a particular resolution of this trilemma, privileging national sovereignty and democratic responsiveness (to economic dislocation in American manufacturing communities) over deeper international economic integration. This framework helps explain why economically suboptimal policies might nonetheless prove politically sustainable, reflecting legitimate tensions between market efficiency and democratic legitimacy that technocratic trade policies have traditionally neglected.

Finally, Schwartz’s (2019) analysis of state-market relations provides essential context for understanding divergent responses to American trade weaponization across different political economies. Schwartz demonstrates how varieties of capitalism—from American market liberalism to Chinese state capitalism and European social market models—produce distinct strategic approaches to economic statecraft and industrial policy. These institutional differences help explain why targeted economies have responded differently to Trump’s tariffs—with China accelerating state-led industrial policies, Europe strengthening regional integration mechanisms, and middle powers pursuing sophisticated hedging strategies. These differentiated responses suggest that rather than imposing a uniform American-led order, Trump’s trade policies may accelerate the emergence of competing economic models with distinct governance arrangements.

Together, these theoretical perspectives reveal that Trump’s tariff regime represents more than a momentary policy deviation—it reflects fundamental structural tensions in the international system as power shifts, domestic political bargains evolve, and distinct varieties of capitalism compete for influence in shaping future economic governance. Any sustainable reconfiguration of international economic order must address not only specific trade policies but also these deeper structural forces that will continue to shape geo-economic competition regardless of immediate policy choices.

Conclusion: Toward a Geo-Economic Reckoning

Donald Trump’s tariff-driven trade war marks a critical juncture in the evolution of the global economic system—one that has exposed deep structural vulnerabilities in the postwar liberal order and accelerated the shift toward a fragmented, multipolar world economy. From a geo-economic perspective, the Trump administration’s aggressive, unilateral approach to trade weaponization represents not merely a deviation from economic orthodoxy but a calculated strategic maneuver within a broader framework wherein national power is increasingly projected through economic rather than purely military means.

By transforming tariffs into political tools wielded for leverage rather than instruments of mutually negotiated industrial policy, Trump has fundamentally redefined the rules of global economic engagement. The United States, once the linchpin of free trade and economic multilateralism, has unilaterally undermined the institutions it helped create, hollowed out the normative foundations of economic cooperation, and eroded trust among allies and partners. This has not only triggered retaliatory measures and legal disputes but also prompted key trading partners—most notably China, the European Union, and emerging economies such as India and Vietnam—to recalibrate their trade relationships and diversify their economic dependencies away from American markets.

The consequences of this geo-economic restructuring are far-reaching and multidimensional. First, Trump’s tariff measures have sparked short-term market volatility and installed long-term uncertainty in global supply chains, disrupting sectors from agriculture to advanced semiconductors. Second, they have disproportionately impacted the Global South, where smaller, trade-dependent economies now find themselves squeezed between great-power economic rivalries with limited room for policy maneuver. Third, the weaponization of trade has systematically blurred the line between economic policy and national security considerations, as evidenced in U.S. restrictions on strategic technologies and critical materials, prompting similar defensive measures by China and other economic competitors.

At a more fundamental level, Trump’s tariffs have catalyzed comprehensive geo-economic reordering. Middle powers such as Japan, South Korea, and Germany have begun pursuing sophisticated hedging strategies—strengthening regional trade pacts, investing in industrial resilience, and pivoting toward bilateral agreements outside the sphere of U.S. influence. Meanwhile, China has seized the opportunity presented by American retrenchment to advance its own economic leadership agenda through initiatives like the Belt and Road and assert greater influence in global trade governance structures.

What emerges from this analysis is the specter of a fragmented, increasingly insecure economic landscape where trust in the global trading system has been fundamentally eroded, and economic nationalism is resurgent across major economies. The liberal economic order—once predicated on open markets, shared rules, and American leadership—is giving way to a multipolar regime defined by selective decoupling, competing regional blocs, and the routine use of economic coercion as an instrument of statecraft.

From a geo-economic perspective, Trump’s tariff tantrum reveals the profound fragility of a system that placed excessive faith in market integration without adequate safeguards for fairness, resilience, or strategic coherence. It serves as a stark reminder that in the absence of credible multilateral frameworks and ethical leadership, trade becomes a tool not for peace or shared prosperity, but for competition, coercion, and exclusion. As the world continues to reckon with the fallout from this radical reorientation of American trade policy, a fundamental question looms: can the global economy be rewired for equitable interdependence and collective resilience, or will it spiral further into transactionalism and geo-economic disorder? The answer lies not in technocratic solutions alone, but in the political will to construct a new global economic architecture—one grounded in principles of justice, sustainability, and strategic cooperation rather than narrow nationalism and zero-sum competition.

Appendixes

Appendix A: Trump Administration Tariff Structure and Rates

Table A1: Trump Administration Tariff Rates by Country (2025)

Country/RegionTariff Rate (%)Notes
Global Baseline10%Applied to all imports
China54%Includes 20% previously imposed duties plus 34% “tit-for-tat” formula
European Union20%Applied despite longstanding security partnership
Vietnam46%Applied to emerging manufacturing hub
Japan24%Traditional ally and security partner
South Korea25%Traditional ally and security partner
India26%Emerging economy
Cambodia49%Developing economy with high vulnerability
Taiwan32%Strategic partner in semiconductor production

Source: Data compiled from “Weaponizing Trade” document, reflecting White House documents cited in the text.

Table A2: Methodology for “Reciprocal” Tariff Calculation

ComponentDescription
FormulaU.S. trade deficit with country ÷ Country’s exports to the United States
JustificationPresented as measure of unfair trade practices
Economic FoundationNo established foundation in economic theory or empirical evidence
ApplicationApplied indiscriminately across allies and competitors

Source: Analysis of Trump administration’s tariff methodology as described in “Weaponizing Trade” document.

Appendix B: Market Reactions to Tariff Announcements

Table B1: Initial Market Responses to Trump’s Tariff Announcements

Market/IndexPercentage ChangeComparison
European STOXX 600-2.7%Temporary plummet
France’s CAC 40-3.3%Deeper than regional average
Germany’s DAX-3.1%Major European economy
U.S. Broad Market Indices-4.0%Worst performance since September 2022
NYSE Declining/Advancing Ratio6:1Indicating widespread market contraction

Source: Market data reported in “Weaponizing Trade” document.

Appendix C: Distributional Economic Impacts

Table C1: Estimated Fiscal Impact of Trump Tariff Regime

Impact MeasureEstimated ValueNotes
Annual Fiscal ImpactApproaching $1 trillionEquivalent to massive tax increase
Per Household BurdenApproximately $7,000Disproportionately affects middle and low-income households
Primary Impact GroupLower-income householdsSpend larger proportion of income on consumption
Secondary EffectsInflationary pressureFurther eroding purchasing power

Source: Economic impact estimates cited in “Weaponizing Trade” document.

Appendix D: Geo-Economic Framework Components

Table D1: Key Theoretical Components of Geo-Economic Analysis

Theoretical ComponentKey ContributorsCore Concept
Geo-EconomicsBlackwill & Harris (2016), Luttwak (1990)Use of economic instruments to promote national interests and generate beneficial geopolitical outcomes
Weaponized InterdependenceFarrell & Newman (2019)Strategic exploitation of asymmetric network positions for advantage
Strategic Trade TheoryKrugman (1986), Baldwin (1985)Government intervention in markets to shift economic rents and secure national advantage
Institutional PowerIkenberry (2011)Role of institutional arrangements in governing international relations
Distributional PoliticsRuggie (1982), Rodrik (2011)Domestic consequences of international economic policies
China ShockAutor, Dorn & Hanson (2013)Trade-induced dislocation in manufacturing communities

Source: Theoretical framework section of “Weaponizing Trade” document.

Appendix E: Impact on Global South and Developing Economies

Table E1: Tariff Impacts on Selected Developing Economies

CountryTariff Rate (%)Key Vulnerabilities
Cambodia49%Limited capacity to absorb economic shocks
Vietnam46%Export-oriented industries threatened
Global South (generally)VariesLimited buffers against economic dislocation
Potential reversal of development progress
Exacerbation of global inequality
Limited ability to diversify export markets
Constrained leverage against U.S. pressure

Source: Global repercussions section of “Weaponizing Trade” document.

Appendix F: Environmental and Energy Implications

Table F1: Climate and Energy Impact Analysis

SectorImpact of Tariff RegimeImplications
Solar PanelsCost increaseHandicapped renewable energy adoption
Wind TurbinesCost increaseSlowed transition from fossil fuels
Electric VehiclesSupply chain disruptionImpeded transportation decarbonization
Energy Storage SystemsComponent cost increaseChallenges to grid modernization
Fossil Fuel IndustryRelative advantageReinforced fossil fuel dependence
U.S. LNG ExportsPromotionHigher domestic energy prices

Source: Climate and energy implications section of “Weaponizing Trade” document.

Appendix G: Theoretical Frameworks for Great Power Competition

Table G1: Key Analytical Perspectives on Geo-Economic Competition

Theoretical FrameworkScholarKey InsightApplication to Tariff Regime
Thucydides TrapAllison (2017)Rising powers threaten established hegemons, causing conflictTariffs as economic manifestation of U.S.-China structural competition
Offensive RealismMearsheimer (2001)Great powers seek regional hegemony and prevent peer competitorsAbandonment of multilateral commitments for unilateral economic statecraft
Political TrilemmaRodrik (2017)Tension between democracy, sovereignty, and globalizationTariffs privilege sovereignty and democratic responsiveness over integration
Varieties of CapitalismSchwartz (2019)Different political economies produce distinct approaches to economic challengesExplains divergent responses to U.S. trade weaponization

Source: Great power competition and market structure section of “Weaponizing Trade” document.

Appendix H: Systemic Consequences for International Economic Order

Table H1: Long-Term Institutional and Systemic Impacts

DomainPre-Trump SystemPost-Tariff Regime Trends
Trade GovernanceRules-based multilateralismPower-based unilateralism
Institutional FrameworkWTO centralityFragmentation into competing blocs
Negotiation FormatMultilateral agreementsBilateral arrangements
Power ProjectionMilitary and economicPrimarily economic coercion
Economic IntegrationDeepening interdependenceStrategic decoupling
Regional ArrangementsU.S.-led frameworksCompeting initiatives (RCEP, BRI)
Strategic LogicPositive-sum cooperationZero-sum competition

Source: Systemic consequences section of “Weaponizing Trade” document.

References

Allison, G. (2017). Destined for War: Can America and China Escape Thucydides’s Trap? Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.

Autor, D. H., Dorn, D., & Hanson, G. H. (2013). The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States. American Economic Review, 103(6), 2121-2168.

Baldwin, D. A. (1985). Economic Statecraft. Princeton University Press.

Blackwill, R. D., & Harris, J. M. (2016). War by Other Means: Geoeconomics and Statecraft. Harvard University Press.

Drezner, D. W. (2021). The Toothpaste Presidency: Economic Sanctions and American Power. Oxford University Press.

Farrell, H., & Newman, A. L. (2019). Weaponized Interdependence: How Global Economic Networks Shape State Coercion. International Security, 44(1), 42–79.

Hirschman, A. O. (1945). National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade. University of California Press.

Ikenberry, G. J. (2011). Liberal Leviathan: The Origins, Crisis, and Transformation of the American World Order. Princeton University Press.

Krugman, P. R. (1986). Strategic Trade Policy and the New International Economics. MIT Press.

Luttwak, E. N. (1990). From Geopolitics to Geo-Economics: Logic of Conflict, Grammar of Commerce. The National Interest, 20, 17-23.

Mearsheimer, J. J. (2001). The Tragedy of Great Power Politics. W.W. Norton & Company.

Rodrik, D. (2011). The Globalization Paradox: Democracy and the Future of the World Economy. W.W. Norton & Company.

Rodrik, D. (2017). Straight Talk on Trade: Ideas for a Sane World Economy. Princeton University Press.

Ruggie, J. G. (1982). International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order. International Organization, 36(2), 379-415.

Schwartz, H. M. (2019). States Versus Markets: Understanding the Global Economy. Macmillan International Higher Education.

Author

  • Professor Habib Al Badawi

    Habib Badawi is Professor of International Relations and Japanese History at Lebanese University. He is also the coordinator of American Studies and a sought-after academic consultant. Professor Al-Badawi was awarded "The Academic Figure of 2018" by the "Asian Cultural Center" for his persistent efforts in promoting Japanese studies worldwide. Dr. Habib Al-Badawi has published multiple books and research papers on contemporary topics related to international relations and geopolitics.

Leave a Comment

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *